One Factor to Bind Them
Professor William Sharpe won the 1990 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for developing the capital asset pricing model, which, among other aspects, asserted that a stock’s expected return depended upon only a single factor: its “beta.” Its Greek name aside, the statistic is straightforward. Beta measures how a stock’s price tends to change, based on the market’s overall performance. By convention, the market beta is set at 1.0. Thus, stocks with betas of 1.20 will typically move 20% further than the averages, while those with betas of 0.70 will shift 30% less.
Sharpe’s insight was that because investors can diversify to protect against other equity-related risks, such as the possibility that specific companies or industries will founder, what matters for determining a portfolio’s expected return is its aggregate beta—the asset-weighted average of its equity holdings. Per Sharpe’s analysis, beta cannot foretell how the overall market will fare, but it can suggest the level of a portfolio’s returns, assuming a given stock market result.
To be sure, beta cannot specify every company’s outcome. It describes the conduct of large numbers, not single situations. Thus, when Berkshire Hathaway BRK.A and Enron each faced a losing stock market in 2001, while possessing similar betas, Warren Buffett’s firm managed a small profit while the latter lost 97%. In addition, betas cannot be determined in advance. They can be estimated from stocks’ historic returns but not definitively known before the fact.
All fine. Nobody expects beta to predict either individual stocks or portfolio performances over short periods. Sharpe’s hypothesis addresses general long-term actions. To cite one example, it implies that if the stock market were to increase over several decades, then growth stocks should outgain value stocks, because on average growth stocks typically have higher betas.
Real-World Results
Therein lies the problem for Sharpe’s model. When the professor first floated his concept in 1964, nobody could refute it. The capital asset pricing model was based on theory, not observation. In those days, finance professors were few and high-powered computers rare. The research had not been done to assess whether, in fact, beta had explained equity returns.
By the time that Sharpe received his Nobel Memorial Prize, that task had been completed—and its findings were devastating. Concluded future Nobel laureate Eugene Fama, who (along with Kenneth French) refuted Sharpe’s thesis, “Beta as the sole variable in explaining returns on stocks is dead.” The wording was kind. Not only had the authors discovered no link between beta and stock performances, but they had also shown that value stocks had walloped growth stocks. Less risk, more return!
The Field Test
In November 1992, Vanguard launched two style-index funds, which divided the S&P 500 into opposing segments: Vanguard Growth Index VIGRX and Vanguard Value Index VIVAX. For the first time, albeit indirectly (as these investments were not officially built to deliver high and low betas, but they did so in practice), observers could readily test whether beta operated as advertised.
For the first decade during those funds’ existence, it did not. As expected, Vanguard Growth Index’s beta was well above that of Vanguard Value Index. Its returns were closer to the mark, but they nevertheless trailed through a mostly rising market, which (again) was not how beta was supposed to work.
The First 10 Years
(Annualized total return % and betas, December 1992 - November 2002)
After that result, academic opinion was almost entirely united. Another 10 years of value-stock success, after the data demonstrating their past superiority had been published for all to see, confirmed the researchers’ initial suspicions. Whether value stocks won because investors were irrationally wary of them, as behavioral economists argued, or because they carried meaningful risks that the beta measure overlooked, as Fama maintained (at least initially), the reality had been ascertained. Beta was well and truly dead.
Except that it wasn’t. Since Vanguard’s style-index funds celebrated their 10th birthday, the pattern has neatly been reversed. Not each funds’ beta. Over the next 21 years, they remained almost unchanged. Once again, Vanguard Growth Index’s beta surpassed that of Vanguard Value Index, although the gap did narrow slightly. But the relative returns flipped, with Vanguard Growth Index outgaining its sibling by almost 2 percentage points per year.
Since Then
(Annualized total return % and betas, December 2002 - December 2023)
Assessing the post-1992 record in this fashion, by splitting the results into a 10-year period and then a 21-year stretch, is of course an arbitrary decision. I did so to demonstrate how thoroughly beta had been discredited by the early 2000s, when its predictive power appeared nonexistent. A fairer approach to the data is to avoid such tricks by presenting the 31-year record in its entirety.
The table below does that, along with showing the predicted return for each fund per Sharpe’s formulation (which requires in addition to the stock market’s results the rate of risk-free return, which averaged 2.31% over the period).
The Full Period
(Annualized total return % and betas, December 1992 - December 2023)
Almost perfect! At least with Vanguard’s paired style-index funds, beta has fully justified Professor Sharpe’s insight.
Final Thoughts
Few investment theories have truly been validated. It’s clear that for developed nations with healthy economies, stocks will almost always outgain bonds, over time. (That statement may not necessarily hold for emerging countries, which is a topic that I will soon address in another article.)
No special insight is required for that observation. In June 2003, a 30-year Treasury bond paid an annual $48.10 for each $1,000 par value. It still does today. Meanwhile, one share of Microsoft MSFT stock in June 2003 earned the right to $1.37 of the company’s operating cash flow. The current amount is $11.79. True, Microsoft has been unusually successful, but the principle remains. In aggregate, companies grow their businesses rapidly enough to reward their shareholders.
After that, though, investment theory is just that—a theory. The hypothesis may eventually be ratified, but it also could be incorrect. Or, more likely, it contains some truth but not enough to serve as a meaningful predictor. That precept is worth considering the next time a fund marketer presents an investment strategy that has been “proved” by academic research.